Background Image
Previous Page  24 / 116 Next Page
Basic version Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 24 / 116 Next Page
Page Background

EuroWire – September 2009

22

Transat lant ic Cable

The climate bill

By a narrow seven-vote margin, one house

of the US Congress moves to limit the

emissions blamed for warming of the planet

On 26

th

June, the House of Representatives approved 219 to 212

the landmark American Clean Energy and Security Act (“ACES”).

Also known as the Waxman-Markley comprehensive energy bill

(after its sponsors), or the “climate bill,” the legislation faces even

tougher sledding in the Senate.

At the heart of the Waxman-Markey global warming reduction

plan is cap-and-trade, a market-based system that limits

emissions but allows companies to buy permits for additional

emissions from others that emit under the maximum.

Presumably a market for these permits will increase the cost of

using carbon-based energy (notably electricity from coal), which

will in turn reduce demand. The number of permits is to be

reduced over time.

President Barack Obama’s commitment to the climate bill

is intense, and his leverage in the Senate has likely been

strengthened by the seating of Al Franken, of Minnesota, a

member of the president’s Democratic Party, after a protracted

dispute over vote counts. Assuming that Mr Obama succeeds

in getting ACES through Congress, over the misgivings of

business-orientated senators, one thing seems clear: the virtuous

results of the legislation will come at a price.

In the course of a broad analysis of Waxman-Markley (“Will the

Global Warming Bill Cool the Global Economy?” Forbes, 2

nd

July),

Nouriel Roubini, a professor at the Stern Business School of New

York University, considered its probable effect in the United

States. Here, much abbreviated, are his views on the climate bill

in three critical areas: cost estimates, sector-by-sector impact,

and trade concerns.

Cost estimates

Predictions of the total economic costs of the cap-and-trade

programme described in the bill vary widely. According to the

Congressional Budget Office (CBO), the net annual cost of the

programme in 2020 would be $22 billion – or about $175 per

American household. Other estimates put the ultimate cost

much higher. The Heritage Foundation [a Washington-based

conservative think tank] concludes that cap-and-trade would

cost the economy $161 billion by 2020 – or about $1,870

per household. Such estimates do not necessarily account

for changes in the price of energy that would occur naturally

as diminishing investment limits production of fossil fuel-

based energy.

Sector-by-sector impact

Utilities are likely to be the most affected by the new price

of carbon, especially in those regions that derive much

of their power from coal-fired plants. The Midwest, the

country’s manufacturing base and the home of many of its

coal-fired plants, seems particularly vulnerable. (Allowances

in the legislation are intended to find the funds to improve

competitiveness of coal plants.)

The oil and metals sectors may also be vulnerable. Some

analysts worry that emissions standards would encourage

companies to keep inventories low and to import more refined

fuels, contributing to idled capacity in US refineries. However,

it may also encourage the creation of cleaner processes or the

development of carbon-capture technologies, which are as yet

far from being commercial.

Trade concerns

The risk that higher costs might accelerate a decline in the US

manufacturing base, as more production is moved offshore, has

prompted concern that compensatory import taxes might be

placed on carbon-intensive imported goods.

In saluting the passage of the climate bill in the House, President

Obama insisted that the US must not discriminate against

imports: doing so might lead to retaliatory protectionism.

Paul Krugman [winner of the Nobel Prize in economics in

2008] suggested that the expressed view of the World Trade

Organization toward import taxes – that they might be

WTO-compliant in certain circumstances – is in line with its view

of value added taxes.

It has been pointed out elsewhere that administration of the

carbon-cap system could become very complex, with a variety

of different country-specific caps, tariffs, and remedies. Also,

even as developing countries petition for trade restrictions on

carbon-reducing technologies to be lifted, or for technology

transfer, companies that developed the expertise have been

reluctant to cut their prices.

Tucked away in Prof Roubini’s analysis is this encouraging note:

“Overall, businesses have supported establishing a climate

regime, given that clarity over regulatory responses is key to

planning.” However, he said, “There are still many uncertainties

about how such a regime will be implemented.”

Waxman-Markey – if it is enacted – is a start.

In brief . . .

Citing an Obama Administration initiative to close loopholes

that have allowed American investors to use offshore

tax havens, the Department of the Treasury on 19

th

June

announced that the US and Switzerland had agreed to

cooperate in the prevention of tax evasion by sharing more

information. At the G-20 Leaders’ Summit held in London,

in April, the US had joined Germany, France, and Britain in

bringing pressure to bear on Switzerland and other countries

whose culture of discretion in banking matters may foster

the improper use of hidden accounts.

The protocol, which Switzerland and the US are expected

to sign within a few months, would revise an existing treaty

to conform with a model income tax convention adopted

by the Paris-based Organisation for Economic Co-operation

and Development. The negotiations over a strengthened

Swiss-US tax treaty took place as American authorities were

still pressing the Swiss bank UBS to hand over the names of

52,000 American clients suspected of tax evasion. The US also

recently concluded tax-information exchange agreements

with Gibraltar and Luxembourg.