GAZETTE
MARCH 1989
Defective Building Work:
Who should pay?
Part 2
The Policy Implications
Lord Bridge's analysis provokes
several observations. First, and
most fundamentally, its policy
preference should be identified and
assessed. Lord Bridge commits
himself to the principle that a
person who has been put to
expense in protecting himself, his
family, his business and his
employees, or his property, from
the danger of injury or damage
brought about by the defendant's
negligence should have no right of
action in tort against the defendant
on account of that negligence. This
is surely a principle that contradicts
conventional norms of justice and
that, if it is to be accepted, should
be supported by a clear and com-
pelling argument. Yet what Lord
Bridge offers fails both these tests.
Few people would be impressed by
the suggestion that, because the
loss (on Lord Bridge's analysis) was
purely economic, the plaintiff
should on that account be defeated
without further consideration of
the issue. Of course it is true that,
in every common law jurisdiction,
courts have been wary about
recognising broad principles of
liability in negligence for pure
economic loss, but prior to
D. & F.
Estates
it seemed that there were
at least some circumstances in
which recovery for this type of loss
should be allowed.
Hedley Byrne
was an obvious instance;
Junior
Books
another (before it was dis-
tinguished into oblivion by
D. & F.
Estates).
The attempt to obliterate
Junior Books
should not prevent us
recalling how that decision, in
reaching its conclusion, relied
strongly on the premise that there
is (and should be) liability for
negligently causing a person to go
to expense to prevent injury to the
person or property. Lord Roskill
observed that Laskin, J/s dissent-
ing judgment in
Rivtow Marine
was
"powerful".
Accepting that the costs incurred
in preventing injury to oneself or
one's property should be char-
acterised as "pure economic loss",
this is nonetheless an odd and
distinctive species of such loss.
That it should merit compensation
would in no way compromise the
courts in their general strategy of
treating claims for pure economic
loss gingerly.
The idea that economic costs
incurred in preventing injury to
others from a dangerous defect
should not be recoverable in a tort
action offends common sense. As
Andrew Grubb
12
observes, "it
would be unfair to require the
By
William Binchy, B.L.,
Research Counsellor,
Law Reform Commission.
plaintiff, knowing the defect, . . . to
sit back and wait for an accident to
occur for which he would be liable,
to discontinue use of his property
or else to do the repairs at his own
expense because he had no cause
of action". This comment makes it
plain that separate policy con-
siderations apply in regard to the
different types of cases of pre-
vention of injury: preventing injury
to others (whether or not one is
under a prior legal duty to do so)
raises separate questions from pre-
venting injury to oneself; and
certainly
the
notions
of
"endangering" and "injuring"
property, in contrast to causing a
"non-dangerous" defect, need
closer examination than the British
decisions have yet given them. Yet
D. & F. Estates Ltd.
offers no
significant insights on any of these
questions. Nor does the case
address the legal position of a
person who acquires a product
which he later discovers is
dangerous. If he uses it and it
injures him, is he to be regarded as
having been guilty of contributory
negligence?
13
(The proviso in that
paragraph as to "unjust enrich-
ment"
might
save the day for the
plaintiff, however; moreover,
bringing the defect to the attention
of the vendor or manufacturer
could help his case.
14
If the product
injures another person, should the
doctrine of
novus actus inter-
veniens
apply?
15
A Glance Towards Europe
Lord
Bridge's
notion
of
"atomising", as it were, the con-
stituent elements of complex
structures or chattels is not new.
Article 2 of the European Products
Liability Directive defines "pro-
duct" as including movables
incorporated into other movables or
into immovables.
16
Article 9 of the
Convention excludes from com-
pensation
damage to, or
destruction of,
the
defective
product itself.
17
The effect of
D. &
F. Estates
is to go a long way
towards incorporating into the
common law actions in negligence
the limitations inherent in the
Directive. This is likely to be good
news, by and large, for British
manufacturers but emphatically
bad news for British consumers.
Prevention Costs or
Damages for Self-
Destructing Product?
Lord Bridge's analysis suffers from
a confusion of thought in its inter-
meshing of two quite separate
principles. The first is that the cost
of preventing threatened injury
(whether to the product itself, to a
person or to other property) is a
pure economic loss which as such
should not be the subject of com-
pensation in tort. The second is
that there should be no compensa-
tion in tort for the destruction of a
product, resulting from the
defendant's negligence, where no
other damage has been caused. An
adherent to the latter principle
could comfortably decline to
compensate a plaintiff whose claim
was based on the prevention of
damage to the product: if no
liability should accrue for causing
77