Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  438 / 536 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 438 / 536 Next Page
Page Background

424

VOJTĚCH TRAPL

CYIL 7 ȍ2016Ȏ

altogether dispensed with the inclusion of investor-State arbitration in the investment

chapters of their FTAs.

10

Whereas the relevance, accuracy and possible consequences of this criticism are

highly disputed, it is undeniable that, nowadays, investment arbitration is largely

perceived as lacking legitimacy.

11

More generally, the system of party-appointment

would negatively impact the impartiality of arbitral tribunals.

12

Also problematic

would be the fact that some practitioners act both as counsel and arbitrator in

different proceedings, with the possibility of ensuing conflicts of interest or so-called

issue conflicts.

13

Criticism has also been concerned with appointing authorities and

arbitral institutions for their own alleged lack of independence and impartiality.

14

As compared to tenured judges holding a public office, arbitrators would have an

insufficient relationship to the States whose regulations they are called to scrutinize.

15

For some, it would simply be unacceptable that private individuals rule on the

legality of decisions taken or regulations enacted by democratically elected officials.

16

A second area of criticism involves the arbitral process, its outcome and its structural

features, and the following concerns have been voiced: lack of consistency, i.e. awards

issued by investment tribunals are inconsistent or sometimes even contradictory, and

there is no appropriate mechanism in place to remedy or limit such inconsistencies;

length and cost, i.e. monetary awards issued by arbitral tribunals, but also legal

fees and related costs incurred by parties in investment proceedings, would often

be excessive. A too heavy burden would especially be imposed upon low-income

countries, which would be unable to properly defend themselves against wealthy

10

See for instance U.S. – Australia FTA (2004), Article 11.16.

11

As summarized by European Commissioner for Trade Cecilia Malmstrom, “there is a fundamental

and widespread lack of trust by the public in the fairness and impartiality of the old ISDS model. This

has significantly affected the public’s acceptance of ISDS and of companies bringing such cases”. See

Cecilia Malmstrom,

Proposing an Investment Court System,

Blog Post, 16 September 2015 available at:

https://ec.europa.eu/commission/2014-2019/malmstrom/blog/proposing-investment-court-system

en

(last consulted on 2 May 2016).

12

UNCTAD (2013), p. 4; Garcia (2004), pp. 352 f. See also JAN PAULSSON (2010), Moral Hazard in

International Dispute Resolution

, ICSID Review – Foreign Investment Law Journal,

Vol. 25(2), pp. 339-355.

13

See for instance ANDERSON & GURSKY (2007), pp. 8 f.; GARCIA (2004), p. 353; Public Citizen’s

Global Trade Watch (2015), pp. 14 et seq.

14

VAN HARTEN (2010), pp. 441 et seq.; ANDERSON & GURSKY (2007), pp. 4 f.; GUS VAN

HARTEN (2008),

A Case for an International Investment Court, Inaugural Conference Paper,

Society

of International Economic Law, pp. 17-18 (arguing that ICSID is excessively influenced by capital-

exporting countries).

15

BARNALI CHOUDHURY (2008), Recapturing Public Power: Is Investment Arbitration’s Engagement

of the Public Interest Contributing to the Democratic Deficit?,

Vanderbilt Journal of Transnational Law

,

Vol. 41(3), pp. 775-832, 819.

16

ANDERSON & GURSKY (2007), pp. 7 f. and 22; VAN HARTEN (2007), pp. 96 et seq. and 152 f.;

VAN HARTEN (2010), pp. 451 f. See also CHOUDURY (2008), p. 782; Public Citizens Global

Trade Watch (2005),

NAFTA’s Threat to Sovereignty and Democracy; The Record of NAFTA Chapter 11

Investor-State Cases 1994–2005.