425
CYIL 7 ȍ2016Ȏ
ABOUT RECENT DEVELOPMENTS IN A FURTHER AIM TO REFORM…
transnational corporations.
17
Arbitration proceedings would also be too lengthy;
18
lack of appropriate control mechanisms, i.e. existing control mechanisms would be
weak and unsatisfactory.
19
The recourse to
ad hoc
annulment committees (in the
ICSID system) would prevent the development of a doctrine of precedent, and
thus of a consistent jurisprudence.
20
Moreover, the jurisdiction to review awards
of both ICSID annulment committees and domestic courts at the seat (in case of
non-ICSID awards) would be excessively limited.
21
The absence of a real appellate
mechanism would indeed make it impossible to reverse incorrect decisions
22
and
to sanction incompetent arbitrators.
23
As investment cases involve public interests
and considerable amounts of money, such restrictions would be inacceptable
24
and
there would be a lack of transparency, i.e. the investor-State arbitration regime would
lack transparency and offer insufficient possibilities for third parties to participate
in proceedings.
25
There do exist concerns over excessive confidentiality, of justice
administered “behind closed door” in matters of public interest, as one of the first
main criticisms raised against the system in connection with serious concerns about
the democratic accountability and legitimacy of this dispute resolution process.
While States themselves have established the mechanism and, therefore, their consent
ensures its legitimacy under international law, this may not always be perceived as
such by States and their constituencies. The power granted to individual arbitrators
who are not part of a corps of judges is not well accepted in democracies, and the
number of democratic States has increased significantly in the last decades, which
17
DAVID P. RIESENBERG (2011), Fee Shifting In Investor-State Arbitration: Doctrine And Policy
Justifying Application Of The English Rule
, Duke Law Journal
, Vol. 60(4), pp. 977-1013, 1007 et seq.
See also UNCTAD (2013), p. 4.
18
GARCIA (2004), pp. 355 f.
19
ANDERSON & GRUSKY (2007), p. 27; CHENG (2005), p. 514 f.; CHUNG (2007), pp. 104 et
seq.; EBERHARDT & OLIVET (2012), pp. 34 et seq.; GARCIA (2004), pp. 341 f.; HUECKEl
(2012), p. 621; Public Citizen‘s Global Trade Watch (2015), pp. 4 et seq. and 17; Poirier (2003),
p. 924. See UNCTAD (2013) pp. 3 f.
20
UNCTAD (2013), pp. 3 f.; Poirier (2013), p. 924.
21
UNCTAD (2013), p. 4; Garcia (2004), pp. 342 et seq.
22
CHOUDHURY (2008), p. 818; CHENG (2005), p. 515; GARCIA (2004), p. 342; JACQUES
WERNER (2009),
Limits of Commercial Investor-State Arbitration: The Need for Appellate Review,
in
Pierre-Marie Dupuy, Ernst-Ulrich Petersmann & Francesco Francioni (eds.),
Human Rights in
International Investment Law and Arbitration,
Oxford University Press, pp. 115-117.
23
HUECKEL (2012), pp. 611 and 621.
24
CHUNG (2007), pp. 967 f.
25
UNCTAD (2013), p. 3; ANDERSON & GURSKY (2007), p. 8; LUCAS BASTIN (2012), The
Amicus Curiae in Investor-State Arbitration,
Cambridge Journal of International and Comparative Law
,
Vol. (1)3, pp. 208-234, 224 and 227; CHOUDHURY (2008), pp. 818 f.; EBERHARDT &OLIVET
(2012), pp. 16, 49; GARCIA (2004), pp. 354 f.; GUS VAN HARTEN et al. (2010),
Public Statement
on the International Investment Regime,
31 August 2010; Luke Eric Peterson (2001),
Challenges Under
Bilateral Investment Treaties Give Weight to Calls for Multilateral Rules,
World Trade Agenda, pp. 12-14,
13; POIRIER (2003), p. 926; STEPHAN W. SCHILL (2011), p. 66.