Previous Page  140 / 274 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 140 / 274 Next Page
Page Background

GAZETTE

AN ECONOMIST'S VIEW OF THE

LEGAL PROFESSION

LECTURE DELIVERED ON SUNDAY, 9 MAY 1976,

TO THE SUMMER MEETING OF THE

INCORPORATED LAW SOCIETY IN TRALEE

by Professor Martin O'Donoghue

Mr. Bruce St. John Blake, Senior Vice President,

presided.

Introduction

Members of the legal profession might be forgiven

if they cast a somewhat cold and jaundiced eye on the

economist. Our activities or perhaps, more accurately,

our image has not exactly been of the kind to endear

us to the people in general and to commercial and

professional bodies in particular. Some hold that we

are the contemporary epitome of Oscar Wilde's cynics

—people "who know the price of everything and the

value of nothing". Others recall Edmund Burke's words

that "the age of chivalry is gone, that of sophisters

economists and calculators has succeeded'. Before turn-

ing to my main task of seeking to describe how econo-

mists do view the legal profession—it may be wise to

spend a few moments seeking to "win friends and

influence people" so as to show that the advent of the

economist onto the legal scene should not be a cause

for concern since there are many things where we hold

or should hold common interests and views.

Historical Importance of Law to Economics

It is no exaggeration to say that without a legal

system — a Rule of Law — there could be no economic

system of the type which we today take for granted,

perhaps take too much for granted, as part of a free

democratic society. Such a Code of Law, guaranteeing

the individual's rights, identifying his duties and obli-

gations, delineating his property rights and defending

his liberties against arbitrary attacks or intrusions are

essential preconditions for the emergence of a free

market for the purchase and sale of goods and services,

and for the free organisation of production and distri-

bution Historically the rise of the mercantile system

followed on the emergence of such a legal code as part

of the Greek and later Roman civilisations. In contrast

other ancient civilisations such as the Chinese which

did not successfully articulate such a legal code also

failed to develop a sound trading or mercantile system.

The full flowering of the free market system in the

past two centuries, based as it was on this rule, saw the

emergence of Economics as a subject of importance in

its own right. This importance would never have been

necessary in the previous feudal monarchial or other

hierarchical systems. If decisions on what to make, how

to produce it, sell it or otherwise use this production

are based on commands, customs or other procedures

which exclude the scope for individual decision-making,

then there is little need for economics as we know it.

But once a society has emerged in which to quote the

philosopher Kant, "man is free if he needs to obey no

person but solely the laws", then there is scope for,

and meaning in the study of the economic behaviour

of such free men.

It is not flattery or politeness, but rather a plain

statement of fact that

without the law and the legal

profession, there would be no science of economics.

Any

economist who values or seeks to understand the

operation of a market economy will freely acknowledge

his debt to the legal profession; not all, alas, fall into

this category since there are those who would wish to

replace the market economy completely with some form

of planned system, and with such a command system,

law and economics again become less relevant.

Links with the Political System

A second bond of affinity between the legal and

economic, professions is that we are both the subject of

much attention on the part of politicians. Indeed this

involvement is inevitable. For your part, since the pro-

cess of law-making is essentially conducted through the

political process, you must have adequate contacts

with and understanding of these political processes, if

you are to, not alone successfully administer, but also

advise and influence (in the best sense of that term)

the reform or evolution of the legal code. As for the

economists, it is obvious that any statements which they

might make, or conclusions which they would draw

from their analysis, about the most suitable form of

economic policy, will have considerable political interest

and, occasionally, repercussions. Indeed the earlier name

for our subject was Political Economy and its remit

was an enquiry into the causes of the wealth of

nations: highly unlikely with this lineage that we should

escape the politician's attentions. One solution which

we found for this problem of a too close relationship

with politics was to shed, over a period of a century or

so, the political element in our original title, by de-

veloping economics as a specifically scientific subject;

that is to say, one in which any rules or laws or

principles were to be based on the systematic testing of

hypotheses, and be capable of empirical verification. In

sbort, they were to be emptied of any value judgements,

whether these judgements emanated from morals, social

mores,

custom or any other non-scientific source. By

thus carefully distinguishing the scientific components

from the elements of art in our subject matter, the

economics profession has drawn the demarcation lines

fully, or as carefully as some might wish perhaps,

but sufficient to provide a valid operational separation

of functions.

I do not propose to attempt a description of the

manner in which the legal profession distinguishes its

role from the political process, save to note that you

do draw this distinction, while yet maintaining sufficient

points of common reference and contact to permit the

necessary and permissible interchange between the two

spheres. To some extent our two professions may find

it profitable to draw on our experiences in this realm

since the question of links and interaction with the

political process takes on new and increasingly com-

plex forms in contemporary conditions.

Economics and the Law—General

Having, hopefully, established the possibility that the

economist is not a menace whose advances should be

vigorously resisted, I may now turn to the topic in

hand. The economic approach to the legal profession

may be thought of as falling into two segments : (1) the

application of general economic principles such as

would apply to any industry-be it the production of

goods such as shoes, ships or sealing wax, or the pro-

vision of services, be they those of doctor, footballer or

opera singer, and (2) the examination of those aspects

which are peculiar to the legal profession and which

are of some economic importance. The questions arising

in any general economic analysis are readily summarised

since they are relatively simple-it is the answers to

them which are difficult and complex. First there are

the efficiency questions, since economics is concerned

with making the best use of scarce resources. These may

be summarised as the questions of what to produce and

how, when, and where to produce it. These give rise in

turn to the equity or distributional questions, namely

who gets the product and the manner in which this

distribution occurs.

141