GAZETTE
MARCH 1986
The EEC Directive on Products Liability
P A R T I
by
Wi l l i am Bi nchy, B . A . , B . C . L ., LL .M., Barrister-at-Law
O
ur law relating to products liability has in recent
years greatly extended the protection given to
those who suffer injury or damage from dangerous or
defective products. In contract, the
Sale of Goods and
Supply of Services Act 1980
has conferred important
new statutory protection; the law of negligence has con-
tinued to expand the range of liability in respect of
products, the most notable example being the High
Court decision in
Ward
-v-
McMaster and Louth Co.
Co.
1
Moreover, the decision in
Kearney
-v-
Paul and
Vincent Ltd.
2
though not imposing liability on the facts,
expressed the principles of products liability in fairly
broad terms.
Activity has also been apparent at the international
level. The Council of Europe has established a Conven-
tion on the subject of products liability. More recently
on 25 July 1985 the European Economic Community
has issued a Directive on the subject. The Directive has
important implications for Irish law. This article will
consider some of these implications and seek to place
the Directive in the broader context of international
thinking on products liability over the past decade.
The Preparation of the Directive
The Commission of the European Economic Com-
munities presented its draft Directive on Product Liabil-
ity to the Council in September 1976/ Negotiations
between the EEC countries then followed and, as has
been mentioned, the Directive was finally implemented
on 25 July 1985.
4
The Directive extends only to Member
States (Article 22).
Article 19 of the Directive requires Member States to
bring into force, not later than three years from the date
of notification of the Directive - 30 July 1985 - the laws,
regulations and administrative provisions necessary to
comply with the Directive. It should be noted that the
Directive supplements, rather than replaces, the existing
remedies in tort and contract under Irish law: Article 13.
The Socio-Economic Background
Increased concern for the rights of injured consumers
is, of course, a feature of European and North American
culture over the past twenty years - Ralph Nader is still
regarded by very many people as a champion of their
interests. It is interesting, therefore, to note that the
Directive springs only in part from the urge to solve the
problem of fair apportionment of risks inherent in
modern technological production. The Directive also
stresses the fact that approximation of the laws of the
Member States is necessary because "the existing
divergences may distort competition and affect the
movement of goods within the common market . . . "
The economic arguments for and against strict liabil-
ity for products are worth mentioning briefly. It has
been noted by one expert that strict liability substantially
reduces litigation costs, inhibits socially unacceptable side
effects and reflects the lack of bargaining equality between
consumers and producers/ But the same expert also
mentions some drawbacks:
"Firstly, strict producer liability will have roughly the
same effects on prices as an indirect tax. Moreover,
producer liability leads to a redistribution of income
away from consumers who incur low accident costs
(presumably poorer consumers) to those with higher
accident costs (the richer consumers). Both effects
are regressive and many would argue that on equity
grounds they should be avoided. A second problem is
that in as much as direct product regulation or the
imposition of producer liability is a restriction on the
freedom of producers to maximise long-run profits,
innovation may be retarded and consumers may
eventually be denied products which could have ben-
efited them greatly. This effect will be most marked
in technically progressive industries such as pharma-
ceuticals, where the product comes in very direct
contact with the consumer (for example, foodstuffs)
and where small firms are involved. Small firms have
historically been highly innovative but might also be
unable to compete in the future given the substantial
economies of scale to insurance which arise from
risk-spreading."
6
In Britain, the Pearson Commission also adverted to
some of these difficulties but took the view that, " f or
most industries, the cost of products liability insurance
would be small in relation to other costs. . . " /
The economic arguments range far more widely than
this brief summary. A helpful series of articles by leading
authors from the United States is contained in the
Sym-
posium on Products Liability: Economic Analysis and
the Law.
6
After these very general observations, let us turn to
consider the main features of the Directive.
The Main Features of the Directive
The essence of the Directive is contained in Article 1,
which is drafted with commendable simplicity:
"The producer shall be liable for damage caused by a
defect in his product."
There are, of course, some important qualifications
to this statement of general principle, but the main
notion is clear: liability is based, not on
wrongful con-
duct
by the producer, which (in theory at least) is the
hallmark of negligence, but merely on proof of a
fact,
that a defect in the product caused the plaintiff damage'.
Whether it is all that easy to avoid the elaborate norm-
ative scaffolding of negligence law - the duty of care,
unreasonable conduct, the reasonable man, for example
- is a question we will consider later in this article.
37